How to incentivise the efficient deployment of electric vehicles

Similar documents
A day in the Life... stories

Economics of Vehicle to Grid

RES integration into energy system

Consumers, Vehicles and Energy Integration (CVEI) project

RIIO-T2 Energy Scenarios

The Smart Meter rollout programme

GEODE Report: Flexibility in Tomorrow s Energy System DSOs approach

New Business Models for Distribution Network Operators

Distribution grid congestion management Remco Verzijlbergh, section Energy and Industry, faculty of Technology, Policy and Management

All-Energy 2016, Glasgow. Contributing funding partners:

SMART DIGITAL GRIDS: AT THE HEART OF THE ENERGY TRANSITION

GSGF workshop on Energy Storage,

Layered Energy System

SSE Guide to the Energy Industry. Guide

The retail price a household pays for the last unit of grid-supplied electricity consumed is an

DG system integration in distribution networks. The transition from passive to active grids

Flexible gas markets for variable renewable generation

GRID CONSTRAINT: OPTIONS FOR PROJECT DEVELOPMENT

Grid Energy Storage: Policies

Unleashing the Potential of Solar & Storage. 1 / SolarPower Europe / TITLE OF PUBLICATION

Incentives and Opportunities Signalled by Transmission Charges in Scotland. Iain Wright 03 September 2018

Smart EV: Consultation Response Issue March 2017

Spreading Innovation for the Power Sector Transformation Globally. Amsterdam, 3 October 2017

Aurora Energy Research Limited. All rights reserved. The e-mobility revolution: impacts on the German power market and new business models

Energy Retail & Electric Vehicles Service June 2018

Presentation of the European Electricity Grid Initiative

Decision on Merced Irrigation District Transition Agreement

Smart Grids in the Developing World. Dr. Rahul Tongia CSTEP Sept. 29, 2010

REGIONAL TRANSMISSION ORGANIZATIONS / INDEPENDENT SYSTEM OPERATORS AND THE ENERGY IMBALANCE MARKET: AN OVERVIEW OF THE PICTURE IN THE WEST

Consumers, Vehicles and Energy Integration (CVEI) project

Regulation to Promote Development of Distributed Energy Resources

Power Potential Guide to Participating : A technical 0 guide to the services for synchronous and non-synchronous DER participants 04/10/2017

Rhode Island Division of Public Utilities and Carriers & Office of Energy Resources. Power Sector Transformation

AER Issues Paper Regulating innovative energy selling business models under the National Energy Retail law

Power distribution: contributing to the European energy transition

AGENT-BASED MICRO-STORAGE MANAGEMENT FOR THE SMART GRID. POWER AGENT: Salman Kahrobaee, Rasheed Rajabzadeh, Jordan Wiebe

The Power Potential Project A guide to participating

Fuels Roadmap for 2020 and beyond - implications for future strategy

Evaluation and modelling of demand and generation at distribution level for Smart grid implementation

Case study: Sweden. E.on Sverige's residential electricity bill. Context

Introduction to Charging: Which Parties Pay Which Charges?

1. Thank you for the opportunity to comment on the Low Emissions Economy Issues Paper ( Issues Paper ).

Co-location Informal Guidance Note. March 2018 Version 1.1

Submission to the IESO re: RDGI Fund Virtual Net Metering Investigation Topic

Respecting the Rules Better Road Safety Enforcement in the European Union. ACEA s Response

Recharge the Future Interim Findings

A complete transformation of the system as we know it

The future role of storage in a smart and flexible energy system

A smartness indicator for grids: Increasing transparency on the ability of electrical grids to support the energy transition

Demand Charges to Deal With Net Energy Metering: Key Considerations

Consumers, Vehicles and Energy Integration (CVEI) project

Non-BM Balancing Services Volumes and Expenditure

Our transition to Distribution System Operator Future Smart. 14 September 2017

Global Trends in the Political Economy of Smart Grids

1. Reference: BC Hydro Evidence - Page 5, line 12

THE REAL-WORLD SMART CHARGING TRIAL WHAT WE VE LEARNT SO FAR

Electricity Transmission network charging

Life Needs Power, Hannover Messe, April 24, 2018 The role of smart and strong grids in Europe s energy transition

Unlocking the value of consumer flexibility. Creating sustainable value from connecting homes PassivSystems Limited

Flexibility Beyond the hype

The difference of the wholesale electricity market and operational methods in Japan, the United States and Europe

Issue 23 draft for Nuvve

City Power Johannesburg: Response to Potential Load Shedding. Presented by : Stuart Webb General Manager : PCM October 2014

Electric Vehicle Adoption in the South African Context

NORDAC 2014 Topic and no NORDAC

Response of the Road Haulage Association to Leeds City Council. Air Quality Public Consultation Feb 2018

Spreading Innovation for the Power Sector Transformation Globally. Amsterdam, 3 October 2017

Non-network solutions

3. The contribution of plug-in vehicles to decarbonising transport

Hydrogen & Fuel cells From current reality to 2025 and beyond

Smart Grids from the perspective of consumers IEA DSM Workshop

EDF Energy R&D UK Centre. CommUNITY. Brixton commercial non-wires microgrid. Bucharest Symposium on Microgrids September 2018

Aging of the light vehicle fleet May 2011

UNLOCKING VALUE: MICROGRIDS AND STAND ALONE SYSTEMS

Consultation on Managed Electric Vehicle Charging: Summary of Responses

What is a DSO? A plain English guide

New Rules for a Consumer Centered Clean Energy Transition EURELECTRIC views on the Clean Energy Package

Retail Pricing to Support the 21st Century Distribution Grid

DNV GL Energy Transition Outlook 2018 and our services related to electric mobility

Welcome and Introduction June 2007

Tariff Design Issues: Approaches for Recovering Grid and System Costs

Comhairle Cathrach Chorcaí Cork City Council

Highlights of EU efforts for Smart Grids deployment and the way forward

CONSULTATION DOCUMENT

FURTHER TECHNICAL AND OPERATIONAL MEASURES FOR ENHANCING ENERGY EFFICIENCY OF INTERNATIONAL SHIPPING

Net Metering Policy Framework. July 2015

PLANNING, ELIGIBILITY FOR CONNECTION AND CONNECTION PROCEDURE IN EMBEDDED GENERATION

Integrating Energy Storage into Distribution Networks

Brookfield Renewable Ireland. Response to Review of Connection and Grid Access Policy: Initial Thinking & Proposed Transitional Arrangements

When Grids Get Smart - ABB s Vision for the Power System of the Future

The Role of DSO as Facilitator of the Electricity Markets in Macedonia. Key aspects and considerations

GEAR 2030 Working Group 1 Project Team 2 'Zero emission vehicles' DRAFT RECOMMENDATIONS

NAVIGANT RESEARCH INTRODUCTION

Global PV Demand Drivers

Smart EV Managed Charging

Final Report. LED Streetlights Market Assessment Study

Transport An affordable transition to sustainable and secure energy for light vehicles in the UK

SUPPLEMENTARY EVIDENCE FROM SCOTTISH AND SOUTHERN ENERGY

Natasha Robinson. Head of Office for Low Emission Vehicles Office for Low Emission Vehicles. Sponsors

Changes in European Energy Market Landscape

Transcription:

Going electric How to incentivise the efficient deployment of electric vehicles Ofgem has recently unveiled its new strategy for regulating the future energy system. One of its objectives is to ensure an efficient locational management of the energy system, such that networks allow the transfer of energy from areas of surplus generation to areas of surplus demand. Ofgem also wants to incentivise the efficient development of energy networks in the longer term, taking account of the fact that it is yet unknown how exactly energy networks will be used in the future. In this paper, we examine how the regulatory framework implied by Ofgem s strategy would affect one of the main drivers of the change: electric vehicles (EVs). In particular, we ask how EV users would respond to the incentives embedded in the current and future regulatory frameworks. CONTEXT The fundamental change we witness in our energy system today is largely driven by decarbonisation policies and technological innovation. Decarbonisation policies have radically increased the share of renewable generation, much of it small-scale, such as rooftop solar PVs connected at the distribution level. Innovation provides low-carbon technologies to meet policy objectives by, for example, lowering the cost of PV panels but also creates opportunities for consumers that were not possible in the past, such as producing their own electricity or responding to market signals in real time. The future development of each of the drivers of change, as well as their impact on the energy system is somewhat uncertain. Importantly, the regulatory framework and the incentives it provides will shape that development. To achieve Ofgem s stated objectives, the regulatory framework should offer a set of incentives to each participant of the energy system to behave efficiently. It seems almost inevitable that EVs will be going mainstream in the near future, significantly changing electricity usage patterns within the distribution grid, but also creating opportunities for using their batteries as energy storage devices. We examine how the proposed solutions under Ofgem s strategy would affect the user of an electric vehicle (EV). This includes whether EV users would have the right incentives to charge their vehicles in an efficient manner, and whether the strength of incentives would be sufficient to discourage inefficient behaviour. Where and when EVs are connected to the grid and how they are charged will have important implications for network investment. It is clear that the current electricity distribution networks are not configured for large-scale deployment of EVs. For example, it has been reported that charging just six EVs in close proximity to each other could lead to local outages at peak times. 1 1 http://www.greenalliance.org.uk/resources/people_power_how_consumer_choice_is_changing_uk_energy_system.pdf 1

INCENTIVISING EFFICIENT BEHAVIOUR From a whole-system cost perspective, EV users should receive sufficient signals to connect and charge their EVs at locations and at times where they impose the least cost on the system while also meeting their own transport needs. What EV usage will look like in the future is still unclear, with current deployment still limited to early adopters. However, current evidence 2 suggests that most EV users prefer to recharge their EV at their home; most use charging points that can be accommodated by the typical household connection capacity available today; most start charging their EV before the battery is less than half full; and owners of EVs tend to be geographically clustered. Furthermore, dynamic pricing or smart tariffs are not yet common for domestic customers. While characteristics of EV usage may change in the future for example, with autonomous driving, consumers may no longer want to charge their EVs at home or even own a car themselves it is easy to see how the current adoption and usage patterns cause headaches to the distribution network operators (DNOs). Thus, regulatory and market incentives are critical to incentivise efficient behaviour. CURRENT REGULATORY FRAMEWORK In general, the regulatory framework incentivising domestic customers, which we think of as typical EV users, consists of three main elements: Network access regime; Network access charges; and Electricity tariffs. These three elements provide incentives through price signals. Ofgem has suggested that it prefers the market to respond to such signals, potentially reducing the need for the System Operator (SO) and the DNOs to directly procure flexibility to manage the system. However, if the price signals do not elicit the desired response from consumers, then the SO, or perhaps more likely DNOs could engage in a direct procurement of flexibility. For example, DNOs could contract with EV users to stop charging their vehicles when the network is congested. NETWORK ACCESS REGIME The network access regime is a set of arrangements that establishes the connected customer s access rights to the distribution network. These access rights are currently offered on first-come-first-served basis. Whenever connection capacity is limited (which will likely be the case with a mass adoption of EVs), the firstcome-first-served arrangement is clearly inefficient and inconsistent with Ofgem s guiding principle of relying on market-based mechanisms. Furthermore, any changes to the access regime may have a limited impact on households that are already connected, since the typical household connected today has a connection capacity that significantly exceeds its peak consumption. Any household that can accommodate a new EV within its currently available connection capacity will not be liable for any reinforcements. Consequently, the price signals sent by the access regime are limited. 3 2 https://innovation.ukpowernetworks.co.uk/innovation/en/projects/tier-2-projects/low-carbon-london-(lcl)/project- Documents/LCL%20Learning%20Report%20-%20B2%20- %20Impact%20of%20Electric%20Vehicles%20and%20Heat%20Pump%20loads%20on%20network%20demand%20profiles.pdf 3 Note that to address delays with new connections, some distribution network operators now offer flexible connections using active network management that allow customers to connect more quickly and at a lower cost. 2

The fundamental problem is that too many access rights have already been allocated for the current access regime to give the right incentives to EV users. Ofgem is now seeking to explore mechanisms through which firm access can be more efficiently allocated, also providing a better signal for the DNOs on where to upgrade their networks. Auctions are a common market-based mechanism to efficiently (re-)allocate capacity. These could potentially be applied to already allocated network connection capacity, as long as the transferability of access rights is made possible. For example, households with excess connection capacity (e.g. those not intending to purchase an EV in the near future), could offer their excess capacity in these auctions to those requesting new connections, benefiting both. In addition, high clearing prices would signal to the DNO in which parts of the network capacity upgrades would bring the highest benefit. Ofgem refers to auctions for gas entry capacity, through which existing capacity products of different durations are re-allocated, as a potentially useful model to consider. They envisage an arrangement where capacity is priced by the market in primary auctions and through secondary trading, with access re-allocated in all timeframes to those who value it most. While a potentially useful idea to re-allocate the current excess connection capacity, we note that there are significant differences between gas and electricity markets that may limit the direct transferability of these mechanisms. First, gas does not require the near-instantaneous balancing that electricity does, and therefore there is time to hold explicit auctions for capacity allocation ahead of the capacity being needed. This also explains why in the EU electricity market coupling mechanisms network capacity is allocated implicitly, not through explicit auctions. Second, the kind of liquid secondary capacity trading close to real time that Ofgem envisages does not exist even for gas capacity. When the locational nature of expected capacity constraints are considered, liquidity availability may be even more problematic. Third, capacity trading in gas markets is performed by sophisticated traders. To expect similar trading by domestic customers would require unprecedented levels of engagement or new automated services provided by aggregators and technology providers. Lastly, if the purpose of connection capacity auctions is to re-allocate excess capacity, the supply of such capacity will dry up as more and more households adopt EVs. In sum, while relying on market-based mechanisms, such as auctions, to re-allocate the current excess network capacity may work well in the transition to mass EV deployment, it is unlikely to be an enduring mechanism to efficiently allocate or re-allocate network access rights of EV users. NETWORK ACCESS CHARGES The current network access charging regime consists of forward-looking charges for connecting to and using the distribution network. As discussed above, most households with existing connections are not likely to incur new connection charges if they purchase an EV. Therefore, the main price signals they would face are the ongoing usage charges. Importantly, current distribution network access charges provide limited locational and time-varying signals to end users at lower voltages 4, and therefore do not convey to EV users where and when to charge their EVs. 4 Locational price signals are provided at higher voltages of the distribution network, but those would not apply to EVs operated by households. 3

Ofgem has noted that there are significant differences in approaches to transmission and distribution networks charging which may lead to distortions, and therefore wants to explore whether there is a need for harmonisation. It also wants to introduce market-based mechanisms, although does not elaborate on how that would be done with charges that are inherently not marketbased. While transmission access charges do not affect EV users, with the interactions between transmission and distribution networks growing, there is certainly a merit in reviewing whether network access charges need to be aligned to ensure that overall energy system costs are minimised. One option could be to introduce the types of locational signals embedded in transmission network into distribution network access charges at all voltage levels. We note, however, that price signals provided by network access charges are static and may not sufficiently reflect changing system conditions that would be necessary to incentivise efficient EV charging in more operational timescales. The type of price signal that may be needed would be best provided through smart or dynamic pricing tariffs that have a locational element. ELECTRICITY TARIFFS Ofgem argues that the roll out of smart meters and mandating half-hourly settlement will incentivise suppliers to offer smart tariffs to their customers because they would want to pass on the costs associated with the customers half-hourly consumption pattern. While this may be the case, half-hourly settlement will not further the objective of efficient locational management unless suppliers face not just time-varying but also locational price signals. The theoretically most efficient form of timevarying and locational price signals would be through locational marginal pricing, already implemented in a number of wholesale electricity market around the world. Under this pricing regime, the price signal that consumers face in each settlement period reflects the marginal cost of supplying electricity at the consumer s location at that time. To our knowledge, such locational and timevarying tariffs have not yet been implemented at the distribution level anywhere in the world. However, academic literature has already explored whether distribution locational marginal pricing (DLMP) could alleviate congestion induced by EV loads in future power systems. 5 It has been found that in a system where the distribution system operator (DSO) determines DLMPs by performing a social welfare optimisation problem similar to that performed by transmission system operators where locational marginal pricing is already in place it can successfully alleviate the congestion caused by EV loads. However, implementing locational marginal pricing at the distribution level would require a widespread deployment of enabling technologies, such as smart meters, smart charging and automation. Since this is not the case today, locational marginal pricing at the distribution level does not seem implementable in the near term. CONCLUSIONS The current regulatory and market frameworks are not appropriate to efficiently incentivise EV users. On the other hand, the theoretically most optimal solution, dynamic locational pricing, cannot be implemented in the near term in the absence of a sufficient deployment of enabling technologies. Its implementation may also create 5 Li et al (2014), Distribution Locational Marginal Pricing for Optimal Electric Vehicle Charging Management, IEEE 4 Transactions on Power Systems, Volume: 29, Issue: 1, Jan. 2014.

a significant number of winners and losers. To mitigate these distributional impacts would likely require a gradual transition. Therefore, in the transition to a mass deployment of EVs, the most viable regulatory response appears to be incremental changes to the current network access and charging regimes, while preparing the groundwork for implementation of more dynamic, market-based price signals further into the future. CONTACT US He has advised utilities on opportunities and regulatory and competition issues associated with entering and operating within gas and electricity wholesale markets. He has also undertaken due diligence advice for prospective investors in energy assets within the UK, Europe and emerging markets. Patrick Taylor Director Attila Hajos Principal Consultant Patrick specialises in energy sector issues, having worked with governments and regulators on energy market design, competition issues, commercial and regulatory structuring and contracting mechanisms. He has advised utilities on regulatory and competition issues associated with entering and operating within gas and electricity wholesale markets. Patrick.Taylor@cepa.co.uk Attila is an experienced energy economist advising clients on a wide range of energy market-related issues in both European and US markets, including market design, renewable support schemes, security of supply, market monitoring, impact and compliance assessment, and demand side participation. Attila.Hajos@cepa.co.uk CEPA is an economics, finance, regulation and competition advisory firm with a respected energy practice. We conduct our work from our offices in London, UK and Sydney, Australia. Our staff and associates have extensive experience of advising a variety of stakeholders regulators, regulated companies, suppliers and major consumers on issues related to energy market design, renewable energy support schemes, incentive design and wider economic regulation topics. We have recently advised the European Commission on policy options to support investment in renewable energy sources and conducted an economic analysis for the Irish Government of options for a new renewable energy support scheme. We also have experience in developing and implementing regulatory frameworks in network and other regulated markets across the UK and other international jurisdictions. Call us: +44 (0)20 7269 0210 Visit our website: www.cepa.co.uk Disclaimer: The views expressed are those of CEPA alone. CEPA accepts no liability for use of this report or any information contained therein by any third party. All rights reserved by Cambridge Economic Policy Associates Ltd. 5